Perfect competition or monopoly?

Question:

I came across a company recently which farms mussels off the coast of a small town in Bulgaria, and I started thinking about its structure in the economy. I know since it produces a homogenous product along with hundreds of other mussel farmers, it must be in perfect competition; however this mussel company also sold locally on top of selling to suppliers. This means it was the only mussel supplier (locally) in the town, and as far as I know that's a monopoly. My question is, what would this company's graphs look like? Would it be more like a perfect competition, or a monopoly? Although it is the only supplier in the town, it sells the mussels at the same price if not cheaper to locals as it does to suppliers, which I know unlike monopolies. Would there be any deadweight loss in a company like this? Is it inefficient or is it more efficient than normal? Consumers can buy mussels from the supermarket, but local supermarkets all get their supply of mussels from this one local company. Please help me understand!

Answer:

The local mussel farm has a cost advantage in supplying in its own town mostly because it saves on transportation costs. Even with that cost advantage, the local firm may not be able to fully exert monopoly power on the local market. It is easy to imagine that farms in nearby villages could compete on the local market. The existence of that potential competition will limit the market power of the local farm depending on the cost of producing mussels locally, transportation cost and the price of mussels coming from outside of the village. There are two cases to consider.

The first case is when the local farm is constrained by outside competition. Figure 1 illustrates. Let’s begin by considering the situation where the local farm does not sell in town and that all mussels are imported from outside. In such a case, the price is given by the conditions prevailing in the total mussel market and the cost of transportation to the local market. Consumers then buy a quantity of mussel equal to Q* at a price P*. If the local farm decides to sell on the local market, it cannot sell at a price above P* if we assume that mussels are a homogenous product. This means that outside competition has the potential to constrain the ability of the local farm to charge its monopoly price.

The blue dash line in figure 1 illustrates that the marginal revenue of the local farm has kinks because it is constrained by outside competition. The red dashed line in figure 1 is the marginal cost of the local farm, which is assumed constant. Remember than firms maximize their profit when their marginal revenue (MR) equals their marginal cost (MC). The intersection of the marginal revenue line and the marginal cost line yields the quantity QM=Q*. This means in this case that the local farm sells a quantity QM that exactly equals the quantity that would be sold by outside competition alone. The local farm sells mussels at the same price P*=PM as its competition. The local mussel farm has a monopoly on the local market and earns a profit of PM – MC per unit of mussels sold locally. This local monopoly does not impact the welfare of consumers in the village as they still pay P* and consume a quantity Q*.

The second case to consider is when the local farm is not constrained by outside competition. It is illustrated in figure 2. Here, the price of imported mussels is high and the marginal cost of the local farm is low. The large difference between the price of imported mussels and the marginal cost of the local farm could be explained by a high transportation cost for mussels. In figure 2, the local farm is not affected by competition from outside and its marginal cost line crosses its the marginal revenue line at a quantity QM greater than Q*. The local farm charges its monopoly price PM, which is below what competition from outside can offer. The local farm earns a profit of PM – MC per unit of mussels sold locally. Because the local monopoly sells a larger quantity at a lower price than what outside competition could provide, consumers are better off with the local monopolist.

Overall, the local monopoly benefits consumers because it has lower cost and its market power is limited by outside competition. If we assume a counterfactual where the village is supplied by mussels coming from outside at a price P*, a monopoly by the local farm does not hurt consumers, causes a net improvement in welfare such that there is no deadweight loss.

Last updated on
March 9, 2018

Explore Our Programs

Interested in more answers or studying in the Department of Economics?